Price Controls: Still A Bad Idea (2024)

“This is a great suppressed topic. It was absolutely mainstream from the start of World War II until the Reagan administration.” This is a quote from “Price Controls Set Off Heated Debate as History Gets a Second Look,” a January 13 New York Times article by Ben Casselman and Jeanne Smialek. The speaker quoted is James (Jamie) K. Galbraith, a left-wing economist at the University of Texas. The “this” in the quote refers price controls, which Galbraith appears to favor. He comes by it honestly. His father, the late John Kenneth Galbraith, was a high-level official in the Office of Price Administration during World War II, and he sometimes reflected fondly on the power that he exerted over the US economy.

I disagree with Galbraith that the topic has been suppressed. We opponents of price controls have been quite willing to discuss why they’re a bad idea. If he were to be more accurate, Galbraith would have to say that the idea has been rejected. Indeed, the heartening point of the Times article is that the vast majority of economists, including left-wing economists such as Paul Krugman, reject the idea of comprehensive government controls on prices. But sometimes it’s hard for people who are losing a debate to admit that they’ve lost, not because the topic has been suppressed but because their idea has been analytically crushed. It’s worthwhile, therefore, to say why they are such a bad idea. Price controls cause shortages, waste people’s time in line, sometimes lead to favoritism by suppliers, and, as in the case of oil and gasoline in the 1970s, can lead to harmful regulation that lasts for decades.

Prices and the Smashed Thermometer

When University of Chicago economist Harold Demsetz gave a talk in the winter of 1970 at the University of Winnipeg, where I was an undergrad, he used an analogy that many critics of price controls still use. Demsetz told his audience that using price controls to reduce inflation is like responding to cold weather in Winnipeg by breaking the thermometer. His point was that just as thermometers respond to temperature, prices are an indicator of underlying economic phenomena, namely supply and demand. Breaking a thermometer doesn’t cause the temperature to rise; controlling prices doesn’t cause inflation to fall.

But it’s worse than that. When you break the thermometer, you don’t make the weather worse. But when a government controls prices, it makes the economy worse by causing shortages.

When I first studied microeconomics in the late 1960s, it was often called “price theory.” There was a good reason for that label: the most important topic in microeconomics is how prices are determined. One thing you learn very quickly is that they are determined by supply, which reflects costs of production, and demand, which reflects consumers’ preferences and incomes.

If you remember that simple fact, you are forever inoculated against the view that prices are random and also against the view, made popular by US Senator Elizabeth Warren, that prices rise because producers are greedy.

Consider, for example, the prices of used cars, which, for many models, have risen by double-digit percentages in the last year. What caused those increases? The answer is that demand has risen and supply has fallen. Both demand and supply of used cars have changed because of the reduction in the supply of new cars, which is in part due to shutdowns of production in the first few months of COVID, and due in part to a reduction in supply of a crucial part, namely semiconductor chips. The reduction in the supply of new cars caused their prices to rise. Drivers with used cars, therefore, tended to hang on to their cars longer, causing a reduction in supply; drivers who might have bought new cars responded to the higher prices of new cars by increasing their demand for used cars.

Consider another example: the price of strawberries. Why are strawberry prices higher in winter than in summer? The reason is that the domestic supply of strawberries is almost nonexistent in winter and is very high in summer. Unlike when I was a child in the 1960s, we can now get strawberries in winter by buying them from warmer climes, but the transportation cost makes them more expensive. Notice how clearly the lower supply explains the higher price.

A Word about “Greed”

What’s wrong with attributing price increases to “corporate greed”? The problem with that explanation is not that corporations aren’t greedy. If we take “greed” to mean “wanting to make as high a profit as possible,” then yes, most corporations are greedy. But those same corporations often cut prices. Have you noticed that the prices of wide-screen televisions have fallen regularly over the past fifteen years? Does that mean that the corporations producing those TVs have steadily become less greedy? Unlikely. So greed is not a good explainer of price increases. A good rule for thinking, as Charles L. Hooper and I pointed out in our book, Making Great Decisions in Business and Life, is that to explain a change in one variable, you need to point to a change in another variable. Because greed (however defined) is relatively constant, it’s not a good way to explain a change.

Price Controls Cause Shortages

When the government imposes a limit on how high a price can go, something that economists call a “price ceiling,” there are two possible outcomes. If the price ceiling is above the price that would have existed in the free market, then the price ceiling has no effect. With such a price ceiling the government is telling people that they can’t charge more than the ceiling price, but that’s something they didn’t want to do anyway.

The more interesting case is the one that advocates of price controls want: a price ceiling that is below the free market price. At the free market price, there’s a strong tendency for the amount demanded to equal the amount supplied. The reason is that if the amount demanded systematically exceeded the amount supplied, sellers would have a strong incentive to raise the price, and if the amount demanded systematically fell short of the amount supplied, sellers would have a strong incentive to cut the price in order to sell their increasing inventory.

A price ceiling below the free-market price causes buyers to demand more than they wanted at the free-market price and sellers to sell less than they wanted to sell at the free-market price. The result: a shortage.

We see the results of price controls wherever governments impose ceilings on rents. Exhibit A in the United States is New York City, where rent control was imposed as a temporary measure in World War II and still exists today. For many apartment units, the controlled rent is well below the rent that would exist in a free market and the result is a long line of potential renters for a given rent-controlled apartment.

Price Controls Change the Product

Another effect of price controls is to change the product. Imagine that you own an apartment complex on which the government imposes rent controls that force the rent below what you were planning to charge. For a given apartment, you now have more qualified tenants than you would have had with no rent control. So your incentive to maintain the property and to furnish amenities such as parking decreases. Further pushing you in that direction is the fact that you have less revenue to pay for maintenance and amenities. The product changes.

In “Price Controls,” published in David R. Henderson, ed., The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, Rutgers University economist Hugh Rockoff points out that because of US price controls during World War II, “fat was added to hamburger” and “candy bars were made smaller and of inferior ingredients.”

We saw a major change in the product when the Nixon price controls on oil and gasoline, first imposed on August 15, 1971, collided with the world price of oil, which OPEC raised from about $3 per barrel to about $11 per barrel during the fall of 1973. The Nixon price controls set the price of so-called “old oil” at $4.25 and later $5.25 per barrel. Gasoline prices were allowed to rise to reflect that price increase but not to reflect the world price of $11 per barrel. With the United States importing much of its oil, that was a huge problem. At the artificially low price of gasoline that resulted, there were line-ups for gasoline in the fall of 1973 and the winter and spring of 1974. I’m old enough to remember that when you pulled into a gasoline station, a gasoline station attendant washed your windshield and, if you wanted, you could get a high-quality map inside the station for free. Both of those aspects of the product disappeared over a few months.

Price Controls Waste People’s Time

Because price controls cause shortages, we consumers start competing with each other by spending time in line. That’s what happened with the gasoline shortages in the 1970s. We can waste so much time in line that the time cost plus the money cost can actually exceed what the free market price would have been. During the 1979 gasoline line-ups, one would often line up for thirty minutes to get gasoline. Imagine that you wanted to buy ten gallons. At the time the regulated price was about $1 a gallon. But a reasonable estimate of the average time value of someone in line was about $8 an hour. So the true cost of the gasoline was not the $10 in money but $10 plus $4 in time, for a total of $14. That’s $1.40 per gallon. At the time, energy economists at the newly formed Department of Energy estimated that ending the price controls would cause the price of gasoline to rise to $1.20 per gallon. With no price controls and no lineups, the time cost would have been trivial. So gasoline price controls actually made gasoline more expensive.

Price Controls Often Lead to Favoritism

When there are no price controls, competition is the great leveler. A seller typically cares about making money, no matter who is spending it. But when the government imposes a price ceiling, a seller, facing more demand than he can supply, has no incentive not to play favorites. A gasoline station owner, for example, might favor his neighbors and friends over strangers. A white landlord who is not fond of black people will find that the cost of discriminating against blacks will fall close to zero. Indeed, the above-mentioned Harold Demsetz, sifting through the classified ads for apartments in the World War II–era Chicago Tribune, found that as the wartime shortage of apartments got worse year by year, presumably because the regulated rent was further and further below the free-market rent, the percent of ads that specified either “Restricted” (meaning that blacks were not welcome) or that the tenant would have to buy the furniture (presumably at an above-market price) increased.

Price Controls Can Lead to Regulation of Our Lives

When the Nixon and Ford administrations saw the damage that price controls on oil and gasoline were doing, they could have pulled the plug and ended the damage. Instead, they regulated further. Effective on January 1, 1974, President Nixon and Congress imposed the infamous “double nickel,” a US-wide speed limit of fifty-five miles per hour, that lasted until 1987. In December 1975, Congress passed and President Ford signed the Energy Policy and Conservation Act, which, among other things, imposed fuel economy standards for cars. These standards increased over time. Congress and the president did not allow us to make our decisions about fuel economy based on actual free market prices. Even though President Reagan ended the price controls nine days after becoming president, the CAFE (Corporate Average Fuel Economy) regulations have been tightened further. President Carter imposed energy standards on various appliances and those standards are still with us today. “Temporary” measures often lead to permanent intrusive regulations.

Don’t Repeat the Mistake

The negative effects of price controls are many. By creating shortages, they often cause people to wait in line, they often cause the quality of products whose prices are controlled to fall, and they can lead to favoritism by suppliers. All those effects remain until the price controls are ended. But even after the price controls are gone, some of the regulations that came about as a result of the controls remain. Let’s not go down the price control path again.

Price Controls: Still A Bad Idea (2024)

FAQs

Price Controls: Still A Bad Idea? ›

The vast majority of economists understand that economy-wide price controls are a bad idea. The reason is that they prevent prices from adjusting in individual markets. Supplies and demands for various goods change a lot, and avoiding price controls allows prices to adjust to those changes in supplies and demands.

Why do economists oppose price controls? ›

Economists oppose price controls because such market interventions only distort the efficient use of resources. In the short run, price ceilings lead to shortages while price floors lead to surpluses. In the long run, price controls lead to rationing, black markets, and poor-quality products.

Do economists like price controls? ›

Economists generally oppose most price controls, believing that they produce costly shortages and gluts.

Has price control ever worked? ›

Price controls fail to achieve their proximate aim, which is to reduce prices paid by retail consumers, but such controls do manage to reduce supply. Nobel Memorial Prize winner Milton Friedman said, "We economists don't know much, but we do know how to create a shortage.

Why don't price ceilings work? ›

While they make staples affordable for consumers in the short term, price ceilings often carry long-term disadvantages, such as shortages, extra charges, or lower quality products. Economists worry that price ceilings cause a deadweight loss to an economy, making it more inefficient.

Can price controls stop inflation? ›

Governments can use wage and price controls to fight inflation. These policies fared poorly in the past, leading governments to look elsewhere to control the economy. Governments may pursue a contractionary monetary policy, reducing the money supply within an economy.

Why do some consumers tend to favor price controls? ›

Answer and Explanation:

Some consumers favour price control because they can buy that commodity at prices lower than the equilibrium prices. It benefits the consumers as they have to pay less amount for the goods.

What are the alternatives to price controls? ›

One alternative to price controls is to use taxes and subsidies to correct market outcomes. Taxes and subsidies are payments or charges that affect the supply or demand of a good or service.

Why do you think Friedman opposed price controls? ›

He suggested that although controls might lead to a temporary reduction in the rate of inflation, they could not succeed on a permanent basis without creating severe shortages in the economy. Just as Friedman feared, inflation rose even higher after the controls were phased out in the mid-1970s.

Is price control communism? ›

Now communism, a command economy, can be thought of as a system of universal price controls, price controls on all goods. And we saw exactly these five elements occurring in countries which had universal price controls, such as the Soviet Union.

Who loses from price controls? ›

Those who manage to purchase the product at the lower price given by the price ceiling will benefit, but sellers of the product will suffer, along with those who are not able to purchase the product at all. Quality is also likely to deteriorate.

Who wins and loses with price controls? ›

Producers lose; some lucky renters gain; and some unlucky but willing renters don't get a place at all. Price controls distort signals that would help the goods get allocated their highest-valued uses. – Consumers who value a good most don't necessarily get it.

Did FDR use price controls? ›

But these measures proved inadequate and in January 1942 Congress passed the Emergency Price Control Act authorizing more stringent control of prices by the OPA. Three months later, President Roosevelt introduced a seven-point plan to control inflation.

Are price controls constitutional? ›

Thus, government at all levels has the constitutional authority to set prices for all kinds of goods and services. But just because governments have the authority to set prices, it does not follow that governments can fix prices as low as they desire.

Who benefits from price floors? ›

Workers and producers benefit from price floors. The minimum legal price plays a crucial role in preventing the exploitation of producers in order to promote production activities. The price control sets the minimum price limit for different products in the market.

Is price ceiling a market failure? ›

Price ceilings only become a problem when they are set below the market equilibrium price. When the ceiling is set below the market price, there will be excess demand or a supply shortage. Producers won't produce as much at the lower price, while consumers will demand more because the goods are cheaper.

Why do economists support price discrimination? ›

While economists generally favor low prices, allowing firms to price discriminate – charging higher prices to consumers identified as having a higher willingness to pay – can sometimes increase output and social welfare relative to a uniform global price.

What is the most important argument many economics make against price controls? ›

Question: The most important argument many economists make against price controls is that they areinefficient.

What is the most important argument economists make against government imposed price controls? ›

Expert-Verified Answer. The most important argument that economists make against government-imposed price controls is that they are inefficient. Price controls are government policies that set prices for goods and services, often in an effort to make them more affordable for consumers.

What is a price control in economics quizlet? ›

Price controls. when the government makes legal restrictions on how high or low a market price may go. price ceiling. a maximum price sellers are allowed to charge for a good/service (below equilibrium) - shortage.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Eusebia Nader

Last Updated:

Views: 6385

Rating: 5 / 5 (60 voted)

Reviews: 83% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Eusebia Nader

Birthday: 1994-11-11

Address: Apt. 721 977 Ebert Meadows, Jereville, GA 73618-6603

Phone: +2316203969400

Job: International Farming Consultant

Hobby: Reading, Photography, Shooting, Singing, Magic, Kayaking, Mushroom hunting

Introduction: My name is Eusebia Nader, I am a encouraging, brainy, lively, nice, famous, healthy, clever person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.